Best Business Books
2017: Economics
Marc
Levinson
An Extraordinary Time: The End of the Postwar Boom and the Return of the Ordinary Economy (Basic Books, 2016)
An Extraordinary Time: The End of the Postwar Boom and the Return of the Ordinary Economy (Basic Books, 2016)
Walter
Scheidel
The Great Leveler: Violence and the History of Inequality from the Stone Age to the Twenty-First Century (Princeton University Press, 2017)
The Great Leveler: Violence and the History of Inequality from the Stone Age to the Twenty-First Century (Princeton University Press, 2017)
Invariably, the stories return to World War
II. Ten years after the first stirrings of the global financial crisis of
2007–09, economic historians are trying desperately to understand what has gone
wrong. With remarkable frequency, writers and thinkers orient themselves and
their stories around World War II, which seems entirely appropriate: What’s
happening in the global economy and in politics certainly may feel like an
unraveling of the postwar institutions and order. But precisely why that
unraveling is occurring and what it implies for the future is a matter of
debate. This year’s three best business books on economics focus on this issue.
They vary in their pessimism.
Marc Levinson, author of An
Extraordinary Time: The End of the Postwar Boom and the Return of the Ordinary
Economy, is not very hopeful. But neither does he
suggest that something has broken. Levinson is a historian and journalist,
formerly of the Economist (and an occasional
contributor to s+b), who
is best known for The Box, a surprisingly engrossing history of
container shipping. An Extraordinary Time, like The Box,
is an efficiently presented chronology of the global economy since the end of
World War II. Levinson opens at the hinge of this chronology, which he locates
in October 1973 — at the start of the oil crisis precipitated by the Yom
Kippur War. In Levinson’s telling, this single moment split the postwar era
into the decades of freakishly rapid and broad-based growth and the subsequent
period of uneven and unequal progress.
An
Extraordinary Time reminds us just how tenuous were
conditions after the surrender of Nazi Germany and Imperial Japan. With
much of the world in rubble, both victors and defeated nations lacked the hard
currency to import basic essentials, to say nothing of the material needed to
rebuild. Economists worried, or assumed, that demobilization would plunge
industrialized economies back into a depression. Even rich economies remained a
long way from what we would consider modernity. In 1948, Levinson reminds us,
only one French household in 30 had a refrigerator.
But
then came three decades of extraordinary growth — Les Trente Glorieusesin
French, Wirtschaftswunder in German, and the Japanese postwar
“economic miracle” — that utterly transformed the lives of many Europeans and
East Asians. Families who worried about finding their next meal in the 1930s,
and who fled for their lives during the war, suddenly found themselves with
telephones, televisions, automobiles, and well-stocked fridges to boot.
Prosperity brought confidence in government and a feeling of security, even in
the shadow of the Cold War.
As Levinson traces the era’s macroeconomic
history, it is clear that in the 1970s, this era came to an end — slowly and
then all at once. Weaving together data and narrative, he shows how
productivity growth foundered and the irritant of inflation appeared and would
not leave. The social strains that began to simmer in the 1960s boiled
over, politics turned more dysfunctional, and the economic themes that would
dominate the next few decades (rising inequality, wage stagnation, and
financial instability) began to emerge. Faith in the competence and honesty of
government was shaken. During the boom years, rapid growth had flattered nearly
every intervention, making even the most ham-handed central bankers and trade
officials seem like policy geniuses. But in the 1970s, what had worked before
suddenly didn’t. Stimulus programs raised inflation but did nothing to reduce
unemployment. Industrial policy no longer seemed a reliable route to higher
productivity.
Yet as Levinson notes, this sudden
helplessness did not cause an outbreak of humility. In fact, another set of
wonks seized their chance to slash tax rates and regulation, privatize
state-owned businesses, and squeeze union power. Perhaps economies would have
performed worse in the absence of such measures. But the change of tack did not
prevent inequality in the distribution of economic gains even as growth in
incomes and productivity remained well short of the postwar glory days.
That should come as no surprise, argues
Levinson. In his macro view, the golden age was an aberration. In the decades
prior to it, technological innovations such as electricity and automation piled
up unused by the private sector thanks to the Great Depression and war. The
conflict also repressed corporate investment and consumption. Then after the
war, a burst of investment in productive capacity, infrastructure, and
education juiced employment and incomes, and generous government benefits
powered consumer demand. As governments worked to piece the global trading and
financial system back together, integration further propelled growth. Rarely in
history has so much economic potential been unleashed at a stroke.
But since the 1970s, the circle has unwound.
People grew less secure as their incomes oddly failed to soar, and as social
safety nets began to fray. There was nothing nefarious behind all this, in
Levinson’s view. It simply represents regression to the mean. And there’s
no easy fix, apart from an adjustment to our expectations. Although Levinson
correctly points out the fundamental difference in growth potential
between the early postwar period and more recent decades, he is too willing to
accept that things could not have gone better for most people since the
early 1970s — and that actions taken by politicians and business leaders were
ineffectual.
The Decline of Paternalism
Rick Wartzman provides a less fatalistic account of the same story
in The End of Loyalty: The Rise
and Fall of Good Jobs in America.
Wartzman’s book is a meticulous and essential history of the worker’s place in
the postwar corporate United States. He, too, starts his narrative arc
during World War II, as titans of industry met to work out how to employ all
those who would need jobs at the war’s end. Having come through the pain of the
Depression and the sacrifice of the conflict, residents were desperate for
security. If the economy could not deliver — if its corporate giants could not
provide — there would be no telling what sort of political backlash the
capitalists would face in the home of capitalism. In the words of Harrison
Jones, then chairman of Coca-Cola, “Any nation with a great unemployment wave
becomes a seedbed for -isms.”
Wartzman is also a journalist, and a director
at the Drucker Institute. His comprehensive tale follows four of the great
companies of the 20th century — General Electric, General Motors, Kodak, and
Coca-Cola — all of whose executives were members of the conspiracy to maintain
full employment. In the decades before the war, they had not been uniformly
progressive or paternalistic. At Kodak, generous pay and benefits were meant to
foster loyalty, but also to deter efforts to unionize. General Motors, having
hired Pinkerton detectives to spy on and thwart efforts to organize its plants,
ultimately acquiesced to union pressure in the 1930s, but only after the Wagner
Act made organizing far easier.
After the war, as unions gained more strength
and critical mass, GM and the United Auto Workers struck the so-called Treaty
of Detroit in 1950, which established a model for the achievement of labor
peace. The five-year contract protected GM (and later, other carmakers) from
the risk of strikes, while workers received good pay, annual cost-of-living
adjustments (which became a common feature of labor contracts), and a pension.
It also established a set of benchmarks that other industrialized companies
would follow.
As the decade wore on, the benefits that were
extended to workers grew. Some employees received annual “wage dividends”
as a form of profit sharing. Pensions and health benefits expanded, as did
efforts to shield employees from turns in the business cycle. Firms invested
heavily in workforce training, occasionally setting up internal institutes
indistinguishable from university programs. Companies pumped out a steady
stream of consumer goods to soak up fattening paychecks and fill the homes
employees were buying in growing numbers. It worked for everybody in
the U.S. — workers, management, shareholders — in part because so much of
the world’s productive capacity had been destroyed in the 1940s and was
slow to rebuild.
Wartzman concludes, as does Levinson, that
the good times could not continue. But the story he tells is more specific to companies
and industries. As the world’s other rich economies recovered, the competitive
environment for firms intensified. GM, for example, faced competition not just
from Ford and Chrysler, but from Toyota and Honda. Improving technology allowed
manufacturers to automate factory floors and streamline corporate offices. The
macroeconomic environment also grew more difficult. Cost-of-living adjustments
and union wage bargains were increasingly seen as the source of inflationary
pressure, and therefore something to be resisted. Companies relocated their
operations from the Midwest and Northeast to Southern states, where labor costs
were lower and organized labor nonexistent.
For Wartzman, the new generation of
post-1970s policymakers that Levinson focuses on had a parallel in the
executive suite. CEOs began to prioritize profits and share prices over
commitments to employees, and hacked away at fat payrolls. “Any organization
that thinks it can guarantee job security is going down a dead end,” said Jack
Welch, the iconic General Electric CEO who earned the sobriquet Neutron Jack.
“Only satisfied customers can give people job security.” Complacent companies
were at risk of experiencing an assault by corporate raiders. Ronald Reagan’s
decision to break the air traffic controllers’ strike in 1981 represented a
stark warning to organized labor: Submit or face destruction. Even left-leaning
politicians embraced the notion that the computing age demanded flexibility and
the relentless accumulation of skills.
As the Treaty of Detroit was metaphorically
ripped up in the decades after the 1970s, the sense of corporations’ loyalty to
workers was utterly destroyed. Yet Wartzman presents this broad and important
shift as the inevitable result of structural economic change: of technological
advances, globalization, and the increased pace of change across markets. Where
Levinson casts the difficulties of workers as the result of regression to the
mean, Wartzman suggests they are the product of adaptation in the face of
progress. And it is indeed difficult to imagine that GM and Kodak, whose size
and history could not prevent a spiral into bankruptcy, could have maintained
their historical commitments and loyalty to workers and still prospered.
Nonetheless, Wartzman, along with Levinson, doesn’t fully examine or explain
how the intentional economic reforms of the 1970s and 1980s altered the
political climate in which these companies operated.
Mean Means
In the
year’s best and most striking economics book, Walter Scheidel views today’s
economic woes through a significantly wider — and darker — lens. The Great Leveler: Violence and the
History of Inequality from the Stone
Age to the Twenty-First Century is a more sweeping, bleaker
version of Thomas Piketty’s Capital in the Twenty-First Century. A
professor of history at Stanford University, Scheidel packs the book full of
data and historical analysis, including differences in the comparative splendor
of ancient tombs and variances in human height, to present a stylized but
compelling picture of inequality across the whole of human history. Inevitably,
he argues, societies that manage to create an economic surplus become
economically and politically unequal. Within those societies, over time, elites
get better and better at rigging the system to divert resources toward
themselves. Only catastrophe limits the march toward greater inequality — great
plagues, state failure, revolution, and mass-mobilization warfare.
In Scheidel’s view, this has been the way of
things since the domestication of crops more than 10,000 years ago. Farming
societies generated agricultural surpluses, and found themselves with land,
equipment, and stores of food that needed defending. Such societies sorted
themselves into hierarchies dominated by the strong, who were best able to
defend the surplus — or to expropriate an outsized share of it. Control of
resources made elites stronger still, and allowed them to bend the rules of
society in their own favor.
Political and economic inequality carried on
growing in this way until disaster struck. In the West, for example, inequality
reached a peak under the Romans, when a large and integrated Mediterranean
market generated enormous wealth that flowed in wildly disproportionate degree
to elites. State collapse destroyed that market and led to a dramatic fall in
inequality that persisted for centuries. But over time, medieval European
elites built new states, restored commerce, and established tighter control,
driving a renewed upward trend in inequality. That, then, was interrupted by
the arrival of the plague in the 13th and 14th centuries. Mass death resulted
in a scarcity of labor, which returned power to the surviving peasantry. But
when the population began to recover, inequality began to rise — straight
through the ages of colonialism and industrialization and right up to the
eye-popping levels of 1914, when both revolution and mass-mobilization
warfare were unleashed.
World War II was a historically potent
leveler of economic status. In the thick of war, governments seized
corporate elites’ power to run the economy and drained corporate fortunes to
fund the war machine. Much of what was left was shattered by inflation and
physical loss. In defeated and victorious nations alike, the social trauma of
war and the political demand for new rules and institutions that would make its
recurrence less likely led to sweeping changes in the state’s role in the
economy, such as the creation of the welfare state, which enshrined in law the
regular redistribution of resources from rich to poor.
And then, many of us imagined, history ended,
more or less. The welfare state and international institutions such as the
European Union and GATT made the world safe for global capitalism, which
eradicated the threat from communism, brought magical technologies into the
world, and finally spurred development in the world’s vast emerging markets.
But, as Scheidel notes, even as communism was teetering and triumphalism was
spreading, the old worrying trends emerged: slow productivity growth, stagnant
incomes, and rising inequality. Why?
Perhaps, as Levinson writes, it was simply a
matter of regression to the mean. Or perhaps, as Wartzman reckons, it reflected
the ways in which the world was becoming a more complicated place with new
markets and technologies and realities to manage, demanding new expectations
and ways of doing things. But Scheidel’s work suggests a different interpretation.
Perhaps what we have seen is the reestablishment of an even older pattern.
Maybe the tax cuts and the deregulation, the union busting and the trade deals,
the waning interest in public investments and the listless response to regional
economic hardship, the complacency toward the financialization of the global
economy and concentration of economic power in the hands of a few firms — maybe
all of that was, at least in part, the doing of elites who wanted a larger pie,
yes, but also a larger share of it. And perhaps they are not done with their
work.
Of course, Scheidel’s bleak theory need not
be prophecy. He, like Thomas Malthus, may have identified a fundamental truth
about the world just as it ceased to apply. But saving liberal society and the
market economy will require quite a lot of political effort. These books, with
their compelling diagnoses, tell us that we are recognizing the seriousness of
the problem. They also make clear that we are a long way from agreeing about
how to treat it.
by Ryan Avent
https://www.strategy-business.com/article/Best-Business-Books-2017-Economics
No comments:
Post a Comment