Outperformers: High-growth emerging economies and the companies that propel
them PART I
Some
emerging economies have grown much faster and more consistently than others.
Underlying these success stories is a pro-growth policy agenda and the standout
role of large companies.
Emerging economies have accounted
for almost two-thirds of the world’s GDP growth and more than half of new
consumption over the past 15 years. Yet economic performance among individual
countries varies substantially.
Why do some emerging economies outperform the
rest?
Some emerging economies have
managed to achieve strong and consistent growth over a long period. These are
the outperformers. What’s the secret to their success?
In Outperformers: High-growth emerging economies and the companies that
propel them, the McKinsey Global
Institute looks at the
long-term track record of 71 developing economies to identify the
outperformers—and finds two key factors that help explain their outperformance:
a pro-growth policy agenda of productivity, income, and demand that has driven
exceptional economic growth, and the underappreciated but nonetheless standout
role that large companies have played in driving that growth.
1.
Eighteen of 71 countries outperformed their peers and global benchmarks.
2.
A pro-growth agenda of productivity, income, and demand has driven
outperformance.
3.
The role of productive companies is a key characteristic of outperforming
economies.
4.
Changing times spell potential new opportunities for emerging economies.
5.
The global economy could receive an $11 trillion boost if all emerging
economies emulate outperformers.
1.
Eighteen of 71 countries
outperformed their peers and global benchmarks
We analyzed the per
capita GDP growth of 71 economies over 50 years, starting in 1965. Of these, we
identified 18 as outperformers, about one in four.
Seven economies
achieved or exceeded real annual per capita GDP growth of 3.5 percent for the
entire 50-year period. This threshold is the average growth rate required by
low-income and lower-middle-income economies to achieve upper-middle-income
status over a 50-year period, as defined by the World Bank. The seven are
China, Hong Kong, Indonesia, Malaysia, Singapore, South Korea, and Thailand.
We also found a second
group of 11 more recent, less heralded, and more geographically diverse
outperformers. They achieved real average annual per capita GDP growth over the
20 years between 1995 and 2016 of at least 5 percent. The 11 are Azerbaijan,
Belarus, Cambodia, Ethiopia, India, Kazakhstan, Laos, Myanmar, Turkmenistan,
Uzbekistan, and Vietnam.
These 18 countries not
only showed exceptional average performance but also demonstrated consistency
by exceeding the benchmark growth rate in at least three-fourths of the 50 and
20 years, respectively.
Collectively, these
outperformers have been the engine for lifting one billion people out of
extreme poverty, defined by the World Bank as living on less than $1.90 per day. Rising prosperity in these countries has not just
reduced poverty but has also enabled the emergence of a new wave of middle and
affluent classes. Between 1990 and 2013, the number of people living in extreme
poverty in the 71 emerging economies fell from 1.84 billion to 766 million.
Outperformers accounted for almost 95 percent of that change.
Less than 11 percent of
the world’s population now lives in extreme poverty, down from 35 percent
in 1990.
At the same time,
growing numbers of residents of these countries joined the “consuming
class”—that is, people with incomes high enough to become significant consumers
of goods and services. In India, for example, the number of consuming-class
households rose tenfold in two decades, from 3.4 million in 1995 to more
than 35 million in 2016.
Globally, these highly urbanized consumers have become a powerful motor for global
economic growth. Outperformers
accounted for almost half of the growth in household spending of all emerging
economies in the past 20 years.
2.
A pro-growth agenda of
productivity, income, and demand has driven outperformance
While the 18
outperformers vary considerably—spanning different income levels, sizes, factor
endowments, and regions—with the exception of Latin America, our analysis suggests
they share foundations of similar pro-growth cycles of rising productivity,
income, and demand. Part and parcel of these foundations are competition
policies that created an impetus for productivity growth and
helped forge the big companies that have driven a significant part of GDP
growth.
More than two-thirds of
the GDP growth in outperforming countries over the past 30 years is attributable to a rapid rise
in productivity correlated with industrialization: an annual average
productivity gain of 4.1 percent versus 0.8 percent for the other developing
economies. That rapid development initially drives the pro-growth cycle by
creating wealth and boosting demand, which translates into more jobs.
Capital
accumulation—enabled by high rates of investment and domestic savings—contributed
an average of 3.8 percentage points to economic growth each year between 1990
and 2015 for the seven 50-year outperformers in our sample, and five percentage
points for the 11 shorter-term outperformers between 1995 and 2015.
Investment as a share
of GDP averaged 30 percent for long-term outperformers and 20 percent for
recent outperformers, or three to 13 percentage points higher than investment
in other developing economies. The difference in domestic savings as a share of
GDP was ten to 30 percentage points higher.
The outperformers could
tap into higher levels of domestic savings, some of which was required by
government-run pension-savings schemes, and some of which was encouraged by
governments developing strong financial institutions and convenient digital
banking services. Higher domestic savings enabled more investment in
infrastructure, among other areas. Outperformers also attracted the largest
share of foreign investment, almost 70 percent, of the approximately $900
billion invested in emerging markets between 2000 and 2016.
Strong productivity
growth translated into exceptional income growth. Real wages and benefits rose
by an average 4.6 percent annually in the seven long-term outperforming
countries between 1980 and 2014.
China led the way, with
incomes there rising by 8.6 percent annually. Among the more recent
outperforming countries, real wages and benefits grew by 6.0 percent per year
between 1995 and 2014. This was about triple the level in other developing and
advanced economies. Household consumption spending generated by rising incomes
grew about three percentage points faster in the 18 outperforming countries
than in other developing or advanced economies.
Another essential
feature of these countries has been their ability to achieve macroeconomic
stability, even at a time of global volatility, by adapting policies to fit
their local context and changing conditions. For example, governments took
quick action to ensure rapid recovery from volatile episodes, such as the Asian
financial crisis of the late 1990s and the global financial crisis of 2008 and
2009.
Outperforming economies
have also benefited from their ability to tap into global demand growth through
export markets, giving them greater economies of scale. In 1980, outperformers
accounted for less than 10 percent of global inflows and outflows of goods,
services, and finance. By 2015, they had increased their share to 20 percent or
more.
Competition policies
also created impetus for productivity growth. Many outperformer countries
recognized the importance of competitive private-sector companies and nurtured
environments in which they could invest and compete, even as they created
incentives for productivity improvements. Rather than picking winning sectors
or winning companies within sectors, they focused on boosting productivity
within sectors.
As a result, sectors
with a larger share of big companies grew faster, increased productivity by
more than their peers, paid workers better, and realized greater levels of
investment. In some, but not all, countries, governments helped incubate
competitive domestic companies through sectorwide support for infant
industries, including low-cost loans, preferential exchange rates, low tax
rates, and R&D subsidies.
Protection, however,
was gradually lifted as these industries became more competitive, limiting
market distortions. In some cases, support was tied to conditions that
encouraged companies to increase productivity. For example, South Korea’s
import policy in the 1960s strictly limited all but strategic imports and
imposed high tariffs, but the country gradually transitioned to a more (but
still not entirely) open scheme in the 1980s.
CONTINUES IN PART II
No comments:
Post a Comment