AI
SPECIAL Notes from the frontier: Modeling the impact of AI on the world economy
PART I
Artificial
intelligence has large potential to contribute to global economic activity. But
widening gaps among countries, companies, and workers will need to be managed
to maximize the benefits.
The role of artificial intelligence (AI) tools and techniques in business
and the global economy is a hot topic. This is not surprising given that AI
might usher in radical—arguably unprecedented—changes in the way people live
and work. The AI revolution is not in its infancy, but most of its economic
impact is yet to come.
New research from the
McKinsey Global Institute attempts to simulate the impact of AI on the world
economy. First, it builds on an understanding of the behavior of companies and
the dynamics of various sectors to develop a bottom-up view of how to adopt and
absorb AI technologies. Second, it takes into account the likely disruptions
that countries, companies, and workers are likely to experience as they
transition to AI. There will very probably be costs during this transition
period, and they need to be factored into any estimate. The analysis examines
how economic gains and losses are likely to be distributed among firms,
employees, and countries and how this distribution could potentially hamper the
capture of AI benefits. Third, the research examines the dynamics of AI for a
wide range of countries—clustered into groups with similar characteristics—with
the aim of giving a more global view.
The analysis should be
seen as a guide to the potential economic impact of AI based on the best
knowledge available at this stage. Among the major findings are the following:
1.
There is large potential for AI to contribute to global economic activity
2.
A key challenge is that adoption of AI could widen gaps among countries,
companies, and workers
1.
There is large potential
for AI to contribute to global economic activity
The McKinsey Global
Institute looked at five broad categories of AI: computer vision, natural
language, virtual assistants, robotic process automation, and advanced machine
learning. Companies will likely use these tools to varying degrees. Some will
take an opportunistic approach, testing only one technology and piloting it in
a specific function (an approach our modeling calls adoption). Others might be
bolder, adopting all five and then absorbing them across the entire
organization (an approach we call full absorption). In between these two poles,
there will be many companies at different stages of adoption; the model also
captures this partial impact.
By 2030, the average
simulation shows that some 70 percent of companies might have adopted at least one type of AI
technology but that less than half will have fully absorbed the five
categories. The pattern of adoption and full absorption might be relatively
rapid—at the high end of what has been observed with other technologies.
Jacques Bughin explains that while
the technical and economic potential of automation is vast, organizations face
several challenges to overcome before these technologies will be commonplace.
Several barriers might
hinder rapid adoption and absorption (see video, “A minute with the McKinsey
Global Institute: Challenges of adopting automation technology”). For instance,
late adopters might find it difficult to generate impact from AI, because
front-runners have already captured AI opportunities and late adopters lag in
developing capabilities and attracting talent.
Nevertheless, at the
global average level of adoption and absorption implied by our simulation, AI
has the potential to deliver additional global economic activity of around $13
trillion by 2030, or about 16 percent higher cumulative GDP compared with
today. This amounts to 1.2 percent additional GDP growth per year. If
delivered, this impact would compare well with that of other general-purpose
technologies through history.
A number of factors,
including labor automation, innovation, and new competition, affect AI-driven
productivity growth. Micro factors, such as the pace of adoption of AI, and
macro factors, such as the global connectedness or labor-market structure of a
country, both contribute to the size of the impact.
Our simulation examined
seven possible channels of impact. The first three relate to the impact of AI
adoption on the need for, and mix of, production factors that have direct
impact on company productivity. The other four are externalities linked to the
adoption of AI related to the broad economic environment and the transition to
AI. We acknowledge that these seven channels are not definitive or necessarily
comprehensive but rather a starting point based on our current understanding
and trends currently under way.
The impact of AI might
not be linear but could build up at an accelerating pace over time. Its
contribution to growth might be three or more times higher by 2030 than it is
over the next five years. An S-curve pattern of adoption and absorption of AI
is likely—a slow start due to the substantial costs and investment associated
with learning and deploying these technologies, then an acceleration driven by
the cumulative effect of competition and an improvement in complementary
capabilities alongside process innovations.
It would be a
misjudgment to interpret this “slow burn” pattern of impact as proof that the
effect of AI will be limited. The size of benefits for those who move early
into these technologies will build up in later years at the expense of firms
with limited or no adoption.
CONTINUES IN PART II
No comments:
Post a Comment