V
Raghunathan : Indians Are Privately Smart
and Publicly Dumb
In his book Games Indians Play: Why We Are the Way We Are, V.
Raghunathan writes about a farmer whose corn won top awards year after year.
When a reporter asked about the secret of his success, the farmer attributed it
to the fact that he shared his corn with his neighbors. Why, the reporter
wondered, would the farmer want to share his seed when those neighbors also
competed with him for the prize? The farmer's reply was, "The wind picks
up pollen from the ripening corn and swirls it from field to field. If my
neighbors grew inferior corn, cross-pollination would steadily degrade the
quality of my corn. If I am to grow good corn, I must help my neighbors do the
same."
That Indians often fail to act like
this farmer is the principal theme of Raghunathan's book. Using examples as
varied as their tendency to drive through red lights to their failure to
protect the environment, Raghunathan argues that Indians often act in ways that
focus on winning immediate gains at the expense of long-term benefits. What
makes Raghunathan's approach unusual is that his argument isn't a moral diatribe:
He employs game theory -- a branch of mathematics -- and related concepts, such
as the prisoner's dilemma, to present his case.
A former professor at the Indian
Institute of Management in Ahmedabad, Raghunathan in 2001 was named president
of the ING Vysya Bank. He now works for the GMR Group as managing director of
GMR Industries, the group's agri-business division, and CEO of the GMR
Varalakshmi Foundation. Raghunathan also teaches game theory and behavioral
economics at the University of Bocconi in Italy. To relax, he repairs
mechanical clocks.
India Knowledge@Wharton: Your book is titled, Games Indians Play: Why We Are the
Way We Are. What are Indians like?
Raghunathan: In the first chapter of my book, I describe what I believe
Indians are like by offering 12 canons of "Indian-ness." For example,
one of our traits is "low trustworthiness." By that I mean we are
most likely not to cooperate in a prisoner's dilemma kind of situation.
Privately, Indians are reasonably smart -- in fact, we are as smart as anybody
else -- but publicly we are dumb. Our ability to understand the need for
cooperation is very low. We believe that cooperation and selfishness cannot go
together -- which is not true. We also tend to be very fatalistic in our
outlook. We give excuses such as, "What can I do alone? Everybody else is
looking out for himself, so why shouldn't I?"
India Knowledge@Wharton: What exactly is the prisoner's dilemma, which you just
mentioned? How do you use it to explain the behavior of Indian business people?
Raghunathan: The prisoner's dilemma, which was first developed by
researchers at the Rand Corporation during the 1950s, is a concept that has
come to occupy a prominent place in game theory. The problem statement goes
like this: Assume that you and I are co-conspirators in a crime. Each of us is
selfish and coldly rational. We are being interrogated in two separate cells,
and we are unable to communicate with each other. The interrogator tells you
that he has enough evidence to put each of us away in the slammer for two years
each. However, if you squeal on me and help him prosecute me, he will set you
free immediately and imprison me for five years. He also tells you that he will
make an identical offer to me (though you and I cannot communicate). If each of
us betrays the other, he will put us both away for four years. Being selfish
and rational, we have to respond to the offer in terms of what is in our best
self-interest.
Now, here is our dilemma: Should we defect and squeal against each other, or should we cooperate and hold out against the interrogator? You may reason that if I defect, it would be in your interest to defect as well -- otherwise you will be stuck in prison for five years while I go free. And if I do not defect, it is still in your interest to defect, since you will walk free immediately. So you decide to defect. I follow the same reasoning, and I defect as well. As a result, each of us ends up with four years in prison. If we were to cooperate, though, each of us would be better off because the interrogator has evidence to put each of us away for just two years. But for us to end up with that outcome, we need to recognize that the two-year punishment we will have to accept for cooperating is better for each of us than the four-year punishment we would get for defecting and ratting out each other.
Our situation is such that we believe that if we do not cooperate, we benefit more. We put ourselves in the other person's situation: We ask, if he does not cooperate, why should I? If he cooperates, it may still be in my interest not to cooperate, because I benefit by not cooperating.
Although this may sound abstract and theoretical, this is often how Indian business people tend to think. Very often our exporters show samples that are of a high quality, but when the time comes to ship the goods, they send something inferior. This is very much like a prisoner's dilemma situation. You may initially make money because you have gotten something for nothing, but going forward -- in an iterative kind of a context -- you will most probably fail. You will stop getting export orders when your customers figure out that they cannot depend on your quality. They will stop trusting you and start suspecting you. In my book, I cite the example of some Indian companies that had won orders to export powdered red peppers (or chillies) to Korea. Apparently, when the goods arrived, the Koreans discovered that the very first consignment was adulterated with red brick powder. The Koreans emptied the whole consignment in the high seas, vowing never to import this product from India. I read a similar report as recently as last year.
The prisoner's dilemma also explains why Indian companies often fail in joint ventures. We tend to be over-argumentative and often look out for our own narrow advantage rather than trying to make the venture succeed. If you look at the way we behave in all kinds of situations -- whether it involves jumping a red light or dumping our garbage in the streets -- that kind of behavior can be explained by the prisoner's dilemma. I will keep my own house clean, but the streets are not my business. Since everybody thinks the same way, the public interest suffers.
Now, here is our dilemma: Should we defect and squeal against each other, or should we cooperate and hold out against the interrogator? You may reason that if I defect, it would be in your interest to defect as well -- otherwise you will be stuck in prison for five years while I go free. And if I do not defect, it is still in your interest to defect, since you will walk free immediately. So you decide to defect. I follow the same reasoning, and I defect as well. As a result, each of us ends up with four years in prison. If we were to cooperate, though, each of us would be better off because the interrogator has evidence to put each of us away for just two years. But for us to end up with that outcome, we need to recognize that the two-year punishment we will have to accept for cooperating is better for each of us than the four-year punishment we would get for defecting and ratting out each other.
Our situation is such that we believe that if we do not cooperate, we benefit more. We put ourselves in the other person's situation: We ask, if he does not cooperate, why should I? If he cooperates, it may still be in my interest not to cooperate, because I benefit by not cooperating.
Although this may sound abstract and theoretical, this is often how Indian business people tend to think. Very often our exporters show samples that are of a high quality, but when the time comes to ship the goods, they send something inferior. This is very much like a prisoner's dilemma situation. You may initially make money because you have gotten something for nothing, but going forward -- in an iterative kind of a context -- you will most probably fail. You will stop getting export orders when your customers figure out that they cannot depend on your quality. They will stop trusting you and start suspecting you. In my book, I cite the example of some Indian companies that had won orders to export powdered red peppers (or chillies) to Korea. Apparently, when the goods arrived, the Koreans discovered that the very first consignment was adulterated with red brick powder. The Koreans emptied the whole consignment in the high seas, vowing never to import this product from India. I read a similar report as recently as last year.
The prisoner's dilemma also explains why Indian companies often fail in joint ventures. We tend to be over-argumentative and often look out for our own narrow advantage rather than trying to make the venture succeed. If you look at the way we behave in all kinds of situations -- whether it involves jumping a red light or dumping our garbage in the streets -- that kind of behavior can be explained by the prisoner's dilemma. I will keep my own house clean, but the streets are not my business. Since everybody thinks the same way, the public interest suffers.
India Knowledge@Wharton: Is that what you meant when you said that Indians are "privately
smart and publicly dumb?" Why is that so, and what are the consequences of
this behavior?
Raghunathan: Another way of expressing this idea is that we are good
lightning chess players but terrible long-term chess players. If I have to see
two moves ahead, I may do just fine, but if I have to see 10 moves ahead, I may
not. Public interest is like seeing 10 moves ahead, while seeking out private
advantage is like seeing two moves ahead. In the prisoner's dilemma, it is
clear that in the short run, it pays you to defect. It takes you a longer
period of reflection to realize that even given your selfish motive, you are
likely to benefit more if you cooperate -- and if each player does the same
thing, both come out winners. I came to this conclusion through many other
concepts of game theory that I have written about in the book. Having seen how
people think in other countries and in India, I [realized] that Indians would
tend to conclude in a jiffy that it is in their interest to defect and squeal
against their partner. It takes longer to think through that if the partner
also defects, both would be worse off. Unfortunately, Indians often don't think
that far. That is why I say we are privately smart but publicly dumb.
India Knowledge@Wharton: In taking the long-term view, what is the
"tit-for-tat" strategy, and how does that apply to business
situations?
Raghunathan: We tend to deal with the same people over and over again,
even though we may interact with hundreds or thousands of parties over our lifetimes.
If I tell myself that I will never be the first person to defect, but after
that, I will do whatever the other person does, that is the
"tit-for-tat" strategy.
In my book, I cite examples from the
experiments that the mathematician Robert Axelrod conducted on this concept.
Life is a series of interactions of the PD (prisoner's dilemma) kind, and you
deal with the same people several times. I may cooperate with you in an
interaction, and you may cooperate as well. Then I go off and interact with other
people, and then come back again to you. Remembering that you had cooperated in
the past, I cooperate again. Essentially, I keep cooperating in every
interaction until you defect. In the following interaction, I too defect,
remembering our last interaction. Now it is up to you to decide whether to
cooperate or not. If you cooperate, I go back to cooperating as well.
This strategy is different than that
of a so-called "massive retaliator," whose response to one act of
defection is to never, ever cooperate again. The tit-for-tat strategy does not
have a long memory. It is forgiving. It is a good strategy in the sense that it
is never the first one to defect, but at the same time it retaliates against
defectors. It makes it clear that it will not respond to defection with
continued cooperation. It responds to defection with defection, and will not
resume cooperation unless the other party cooperates first.
I show in the book that the
tit-for-tat strategy never wins against any one individual. But in the long
run, people get to know that you are a gentleman; you are never the first to
defect. They know that you are forgiving, but also that they cannot take you
for granted. All these are, broadly, the hallmarks of a gentleman, and so I
call this the "gentleman's strategy."
This strategy can easily be applied
to a large number of business situations. For example, consider a businessman
who normally supplies materials of high quality but once in a while -- one out
of 10 times -- he supplies sub-standard materials. In other words, he defects
one time out of 10, and cooperates nine times out of 10, hoping that you will
not retaliate. He is trying to gain some extra points over his interactions.
Such a businessman is not using the tit-for-tat strategy; he is using a
random-defect strategy. What happens with this strategy is that if one of the
players he runs into is a massive retaliator, that player will stop dealing
with him completely. His ability to collect any further revenues from that
party will end.
However, a tit-for-tat strategist
will never defect first. As a result, it becomes clear to all the players over
the long run that the tit-for-tat player will never retaliate unless they did
something wrong to him first. Unfortunately, in India such business people are
few and far between.
India Knowledge@Wharton: In one chapter you cite the example of the TVS Group, a
company in Southern India, which recognized that foregoing short-term benefits
sometimes helps you gain long-term advantages.
Raghunathan: Yes -- Suresh Krishna, chairman of Sundaram Fasteners,
which is part of the TVS Group, told me this story about his father, T.S.
Krishna. His father had told him this anecdote during the 1960s but he still
remembers it.
The TVS Group, like other traders in
Southern India, imported diesel engines during the 1940s. The engines were
imported from London for about Rs. 1,100 ($220 at the prevailing exchange rate)
and were sold in the local market at a 25% to 30% markup for about Rs. 1,400
($280). But during the mid-1940s, supply was disrupted because of World War II,
and this led to an extreme shortage of engines. Anyone who had an import
license could easily sell the engines for Rs. 5,000 ($1,000) -- many customers
were willing to pay such prices. At one level, you could call this market
pricing since the demand-supply situation was so skewed. It was a seller's
market. But, at another level, you could also view this as a defection of sorts
because the sellers were exploiting the wartime shortage to force buyers to pay
a higher price.
Krishna decided that the TVS Group
would not follow that approach. Despite the shortage and the prevailing high
prices, he insisted on charging the normal markup of 25% and kept selling
engines for Rs. 1,400 throughout the war. At that time, the local business
community thought he was either naïve or downright daft for missing out on the
opportunity to make as much money as possible. When the war ended, however, the
traders who had profiteered from the shortage went out of business one after
another; today no one remembers those companies. But the TVS Group survived,
and it continues to be recognized as a valuable company.
In today's terms, we might say that
TVS had better corporate governance, and its strategy paid off because it
delivered long-term shareholder value. Back in 1945, though, it was just one
decent man trying to do the right thing for his customers. Krishna refused to
defect just because the timing was against his customers. The consequence is
that even today, TVS is regarded as a name to be trusted. If the company lists
its shares for sale, people subscribe to them. If products carry the TVS brand,
people buy them. Krishna probably did not stop to think about the "brand
value" of his behavior; still, his actions helped build the TVS brand.
India Knowledge@Wharton: Why do you think Indians are bad at regulation and
self-regulation?
Raghunathan: I think self-regulation is molded by regulation. Even in the
U.S., when you are driving along a highway, if you did not know that a police
patrol car might unexpectedly appear behind you with lights flashing, you might
be tempted to drive faster than the speed limit. If the U.S. government had not
come down hard on emissions, maybe the auto industry would have not revised its
production standards. I believe that self regulation is indeed affected by
regulation.
In India, part of our problem is
that the regulatory environment is weak. Combined with our fundamental lack of
self regulation, matters tend to spin out of control very soon. As I said
above, we are like lightning chess players and a little too quick to see where
our immediate self-interest lies. When we think we can get away with something
and the probability of getting caught is low, we tend to do whatever we want to
do.
For example, consider the Companies
Act, which governs disclosure of financial information by publicly listed
firms. Today, if a public company does not disclose its financial statements on
time, the penalty is Rs. 1,000 ($25) a day. This implies that if a company is
willing to spend $9,125 on fines, it can go a whole year without making
financial information available in the public domain. To me, that almost sounds
like an incentive for companies not to file their annual financial statements.
How can we have self-regulation when the regulations themselves are so weak?
The reality is that back when these regulations were formulated, a thousand
bucks a day was a lot of money. Today, you would need to charge corporations a
penalty of Rs. 10 million ($250,000) a day for it to be a deterrent.
The trouble in India is that the
chances or being caught are low, and the consequences of being caught are weak.
As a result, we have forgotten what self regulation means. Democracy has been
misinterpreted to mean the right to do whatever you want.
India Knowledge@Wharton: Why is it so hard for Indians to work in teams? Even in a
team sport like cricket, one-upmanship often undermines collective performance.
Does game theory offer any explanations?
Raghunathan: That is a good question, but I don't know to what extent
game theory can answer it. The only thing I would say is that it depends on how
the team players resolve their own prisoner's dilemma-type situations.
If you approach the resolution of
the dilemma externally, you will never resolve the issue. By approaching it
externally, I mean asking yourself, 'If the other party defects, what should I
do?' or 'If the other party does not defect, what should I do?' If you ask
yourself such questions, the answer at which you will arrive is that you should
defect. If both parties ask themselves the same questions, they both end up
defecting -- and losing.
The only correct way to resolve the
prisoner's dilemma is to ask yourself, 'What is the correct thing, deep down,
for me to do?' In other words, what is the action that if everyone were to
follow it, would lead to the collective good? If you were to approach the
prisoner's dilemma that way, both accomplices would arrive at the same answer
-- not to squeal against the other. You need to approach the issue internally.
The problem arises when you expect others to defect, so you try and pre-empt
the harmful consequences by defecting yourself.
India Knowledge@Wharton: To what extent are such tendencies uniquely Indian? For
example, if you have been following the horror stories about the recall of
millions of toys manufactured in China, wouldn't you think these are human
traits rather than Indian ones?
Raghunathan: Absolutely. I agree completely that these are human traits.
You will find them everywhere in the world. The theories I discuss in my book
were not developed in India but outside, and people have been writing about and
talking about them long before my book came along. But one major difference is
that in other parts of the world, the tendency to defect is much lower when you
play the prisoner's dilemma type of games. In India, the tendency to defect is
much higher.
Consider the example about the toys
being recalled in China. It is of course true that in this one dimension
Chinese manufacturers -- or their subcontractors -- did not pay attention to
quality. But I can think of 10 other dimensions in which the Chinese have
chosen cooperation with one another over defection. For example, Chinese people
show enormous discipline when they work in a team. I have seen Chinese cab
drivers stopping before a red light at 2:00 a.m. -- no Indian taxi driver would
ever do that. The number of medals they win during the Olympics shows that they
have systems that work very well.
In Shanghai, in four years they
built out the magnetic levitation train that connects the airport to the city.
Or consider a simpler example. When I was in Shanghai, I saw a newspaper ad
that addressed the citizens and said, "If you want to be residents of a
world-class city, you must behave accordingly and not hang your laundry out to
dry on your balcony." When I drove around the city, I did not see a single
Chinese home with washed clothes hanging on the balcony. In India, it is
unthinkable that you could even make such an appeal.
So it is true that nowhere in the
world are people immune to the prisoner's dilemma. But the incidence of
defection in almost every walk of life seems to be unique to India. This may
seem to be a caricature, but if I am exaggerating certain features, it is
because I want to draw attention to them.
India Knowledge@Wharton: Do you have any reason to hope that the way Indians are
will some day become the way Indians were?
Raghunathan: I am not a spiritual person. But in doing research for this
book, for the first time I read the Bhagavad-Gita [the Sanskrit text
that is regarded as sacred by Hindus]. I realized that the Gita has a lot of
things which help resolve the prisoner's dilemma readily. For example, if you
do your dharma [duty] towards humanity, the level of cooperation could
be much higher. That is what having a good character is all about.
This gives me hope for the future.
As India's economy improves and education spreads, I hope defection will be
replaced by cooperation. My question about why Indians are the way they are is
a rhetorical one -- it is an expression of my frustration. But my attitude
towards India is like that of a parent towards a beloved child who needs
correction. You don't love that child any less; it is because of your love that
you want to bring about change. I hope these ideas will encourage some
introspection about how to make things better.
http://knowledge.wharton.upenn.edu/india/article.cfm?articleid=4222
No comments:
Post a Comment