The real business of business
Shareholder-oriented capitalism is still
the best path to broad economic prosperity, as long as companies focus on the
long term.
The guiding principle of business value creation is a
refreshingly simple construct: companies that grow and earn a return on capital
that exceeds their cost of capital create value. The financial crisis of
2007–08 and the Great Recession that followed are only the most recent
reminders that when managers, boards of directors, and investors forget this
guiding principle, the consequences are disastrous—so much so, in fact, that
some economists now call into question the very foundations of
shareholder-oriented capitalism. Confidence in business has tumbled.1 Politicians and
commentators are pushing for more regulation and fundamental changes in
corporate governance. Academics and even some business leaders have called for
companies to change their focus from increasing shareholder value to a broader
focus on all stakeholders, including customers, employees, suppliers, and local
communities.
No question, the complexity
of managing the interests of myriad owners and stakeholders in a modern
corporation demands that any reform discussion begin with a large dose of
humility and tolerance for ambiguity in defining the purpose of business. But
we believe the current debate has muddied a fundamental truth: creating
shareholder value is not the same as maximizing short-term profits—and
companies that confuse the two often put both shareholder value and stakeholder
interests at risk. Indeed, a system focused on creating shareholder value from
business isn’t the problem; short-termism is. Great managers don’t skimp on
safety, don’t make value-destroying investments just because their peers are
doing it, and don’t use accounting or financial gimmicks to boost short-term
profits, because ultimately such moves undermine intrinsic value.
What’s needed at this time
of reflection on the virtues and vices of capitalism is a clearer definition of
shareholder value creation that can guide managers and board directors, rather
than blurring their focus with a vague stakeholder agenda. We do believe that
companies are better able to deliver long-term value to shareholders when they
consider stakeholder concerns; the key is for managers to examine those
concerns systematically for opportunities to do both.
What does it mean to create shareholder value?
If investors knew as much
about a company as its managers, maximizing its current share price might be
equivalent to maximizing value over time. In the real world, investors have
only a company’s published financial results and their own assessment of the
quality and integrity of its management team. For large companies, it’s
difficult even for insiders to know how the financial results are generated.
Investors in most companies don’t know what’s really going on inside a company or
what decisions managers are making. They can’t know, for example, whether the
company is improving its margins by finding more efficient ways to work or by
simply skimping on product development, maintenance, or marketing.
Since investors don’t have
complete information, it’s not difficult for companies to pump up their share
price in the short term. For example, from 1997 to 2003, a global
consumer-products company consistently generated annual growth in earnings per
share (EPS) between 11 and 16 percent. Managers attributed the company’s
success to improved efficiency. Impressed, investors pushed the company’s share
price above that of its peers—unaware that the company was shortchanging its
investment in product development and brand building to inflate short-term
profits, even as revenue growth declined. In 2003, managers were compelled to
admit what they’d done. Not surprisingly, the company went through a painful
period of rebuilding, and its stock price took years to recover.
In
contrast, the evidence makes it clear that companies with a long strategic
horizon create more value. The banks that had the insight and courage to forgo
short-term profits during the real-estate bubble earned much better returns for
shareholders over the longer term.2 Oil and gas companies
known for investing in safety outperform those that haven’t. We’ve found,
empirically, that long-term revenue growth—particularly organic revenue
growth—is the most important driver of shareholder returns for companies with
high returns on capital (though not for companies with low returns on capital).
We’ve also found a strong positive correlation between long-term
shareholder returns and investments in R&D—evidence of a commitment to
creating value in the longer term.
The weight of such evidence and our experience
supports a clear definition of what it means to create shareholder value, which
is to create value for the collective of all shareholders, present and
future. This means managers should not take actions to increase today’s
share price if they will reduce it down the road. It’s the task of management
and the board to have the courage to make long-term value-creating decisions
despite the short-term consequences.
Can stakeholder interests be reconciled?
Much recent criticism of
shareholder-oriented capitalism has called on companies to focus on a broader
set of stakeholders, not just shareholders. It’s a view that has long been
influential in continental Europe, where it is frequently embedded in the
governance structures of the corporate form of organization. And we agree that
for most companies anywhere in the world, pursuing the creation of long-term shareholder
value requires satisfying other stakeholders as well.
We
would go even further. We believe that companies dedicated to value creation
are healthier and more robust—and that investing for sustainable growth also
builds stronger economies, higher living standards, and more opportunities for
individuals. Our research shows, for example, that many
corporate-social-responsibility initiatives also create shareholder value, and
managers should seek out such opportunities.5 For example, IBM’s
free web-based resources on business management not only help to build small
and midsize enterprises but also improve IBM’s reputation and relationships in
new markets and develop relationships with potential customers. In another
case, Novo Nordisk’s “Triple Bottom Line” philosophy of social responsibility,
environmental soundness, and economic viability has led to programs to improve
diabetes care in China. According to the company, its programs have burnished
its brand, added to its market share, and increased sales—at the same time as
improving physician education and patient outcomes. Similarly, Best Buy’s
efforts to reduce attrition among women employees not only lowered turnover
among women by more than 5 percent, it also helped them create their own
support networks and build leadership skills.
But
what should be done when the interests of stakeholders don’t naturally
complement those of a company, for instance, when it comes to questions of
employee compensation and benefits, supplier management, and local community
relationships? Most advocates of managing for stakeholders appear to argue that
companies can maximize value for all stakeholders and shareholders
simultaneously—without making trade-offs among them. This includes, for
example, Cornell Law School professor Lynn Stout’s book, The
Shareholder Value Myth,6 in which Stout
argues persuasively that nothing in US corporate law requires companies to
focus on shareholder value creation. But her argument that putting shareholders
first harms nearly everyone is really an argument against short-termism, not a
prescription for how to make trade-offs. Similarly, R. Edward Freeman, a
professor at the University of Virginia’s Darden School of Business, has
written at length proposing a stakeholder value orientation. In his recent
book, Managing for Stakeholders, he and his coauthors assert that
“there is really no inherent conflict between the interests of financiers and
other stakeholders.”
John
Mackey, founder and co-CEO of Whole Foods, recently wrote Conscious
Capitalism, in which he, too, asserts that there are no trade-offs to
be made.
Such criticism is naive.
Strategic decisions often require myriad trade-offs among the interests of
different groups that are often at odds with one another. And in the absence of
other principled guidelines for such decisions, when there are trade-offs to be
made, prioritizing long-term value creation is best for the allocation of
resources and the health of the economy.
Consider employee
stakeholders. A company that tries to boost profits by providing a shabby work
environment relative to competitors, underpaying employees, or skimping on
benefits will have trouble attracting and retaining high-quality employees.
Lower-quality employees can mean lower-quality products, reducing demand and
hurting reputation. More injury and illness can invite regulatory scrutiny and
more union pressure. More turnover will inevitably increase training costs.
With today’s more mobile and more educated workforce, such a company would struggle
in the long term against competitors offering more attractive environments. If
the company earns more than its cost of capital, it might afford to pay
above-market wages and still prosper—and treating employees well can be good
business. But how well is well enough? A stakeholder focus doesn’t provide an
answer. A shareholder focus does. Pay wages that are just enough to attract
quality employees and keep them happy and productive, pairing those with a
range of nonmonetary benefits and rewards.
Or consider how high a
price a company should charge for its products. A shareholder focus would weigh
price, volume, and customer satisfaction to determine a price that creates the
most shareholder value. However, that price would also have to entice consumers
to buy the products—and not just once but multiple times, for different
generations of products. A company might still thrive if it charged lower
prices, but there’s no way to determine whether the value of a lower price is
greater for consumers than the value of a higher price to its shareholders.
Finally, consider whether companies in mature, competitive industries should
keep open high-cost plants that lose money just to keep employees working and
prevent suppliers from going bankrupt. To do so in a globalizing industry would
distort the allocation of resources in the economy.
These
can be agonizing decisions for managers and are difficult all around. But
consumers benefit when goods are produced at the lowest possible cost, and the
economy benefits when unproductive plants are closed and employees move to new
jobs with more competitive companies. And while it’s true that employees often
can’t just pick up and relocate, it’s also true that value-creating companies
create more jobs. When examining employment, we found that the European and US
companies that created the most shareholder value in the past 15 years have
shown stronger employment growth.
Short-termism
runs deep
What’s
most relevant about Stout’s argument, and that of others, is its implicit
criticism of short-termism—and that is a fair critique of today’s capitalism.
Despite overwhelming evidence linking intrinsic investor preferences to
long-term value creation, too many managers continue to plan and execute
strategy, and then report their performance against shorter-term measures, EPS
in particular.
As
a result of their focus on short-term EPS, major companies often pass up
value-creating opportunities. In a survey of 400 CFOs, two Duke University
professors found that fully 80 percent of the CFOs said they would reduce
discretionary spending on potentially value-creating activities such as
marketing and R&D in order to meet their short-term earnings targets.11 In addition, 39
percent said they would give discounts to customers to make purchases this
quarter, rather than next, in order to hit quarterly EPS targets. Such biases
shortchange all stakeholders.
As
an illustration of how executives get caught up in a short-term EPS focus,
consider our experience with companies analyzing a prospective acquisition. The
most frequent question managers ask is whether the transaction will dilute EPS
over the first year or two. Given the popularity of EPS as a yardstick for
company decisions, you might think that a predicted improvement in EPS would be
an important indication of an acquisition’s potential to create value. However,
there is no empirical evidence linking increased EPS with the value created by
a transaction. Deals that strengthen EPS and deals that dilute EPS are equally
likely to create or destroy value.
If
such fallacies have no impact on value, why do they prevail? The impetus for short-termism
varies. Some executives argue that investors won’t let them focus on the long
term; others fault the rise of shareholder activists in particular. Yet our
research shows that even if short-term investors cause day-to-day fluctuations
in a company’s share price and dominate quarterly earnings calls, longer-term
investors are the ones who align market prices with intrinsic value.13 Moreover, the
evidence shows that, on average, activist investors strengthen the long-term
health of the companies they pursue, often challenging existing compensation
structures, for example, that encourage short-termism.14 Instead, we often
find that executives themselves or their boards are usually the source of
short-termism. A 2013 survey of more than 1,000 executives and board members
found, for example, that most cited their own executive teams and boards
(rather than investors, analysts, and others outside the company)as the
greatest sources of pressure for short-term performance.
The results can defy logic.
We recently participated in a discussion with a company pursuing a major
acquisition about whether the deal’s likely earnings dilution was important.
One of the company’s bankers opined that he knew any impact on EPS would be
irrelevant to value, but he used it as a simple way to communicate with boards
of directors. Elsewhere, we’ve heard company executives acknowledge that they,
too, doubt that the impact on EPS is so important—but they use it anyway, they
say, for the benefit of Wall Street analysts. Investors also tell us that a
deal’s short-term impact on EPS is not that important. Apparently everyone
knows that a transaction’s short-term impact on EPS doesn’t matter, yet they
all pay attention to it.
Shareholder capitalism won’t solve all social
issues
There are some trade-offs
that company managers can’t make—and neither a shareholder nor a stakeholder
approach to governance can help. This is especially true when it comes to
issues that affect people who aren’t immediately involved with the company as investors,
customers, or suppliers. These so-called externalities—parties affected by a
company who did not choose to be so—are often beyond the ken of corporate
decision making because there is no objective basis for making trade-offs among
parties.
If, for example, climate
change is one of the largest social issues facing the world, then one natural
place to look for a solution is coal-fired power plants, among the largest
man-made sources of carbon emissions. But how are the managers of a coal-mining
company to make all the trade-offs needed to begin solving our environmental
problems? If a long-term shareholder focus led them to anticipate potential
regulatory changes, they should modify their investment strategies accordingly;
they may not want to open new mines, for example. But if the company abruptly
stopped operating existing ones, not only would its shareholders be wiped out
but so would its bondholders (since bonds are often held by pension funds). All
of its employees would be out of work, with magnifying effects on the entire
local community. Second-order effects would be unpredictable. Without concerted
action among all coal producers, another supplier could step up to meet demand.
Even with concerted action, power plants might be unable to produce
electricity, idling their workers and causing electricity shortages that
undermine the economy. What objective criteria would any individual company use
to weigh the economic and environmental trade-offs of such decisions—whether
they’re privileging shareholders or stakeholders?
In some cases, individual
companies won’t be able to satisfy all stakeholders. For any individual
company, the complexity of addressing universal social issues such as climate
change leaves us with an unresolved question: If not them, then who? Some might
argue that it would be better for the government to develop incentives,
regulations, and taxes, for example, to encourage a migration away from
polluting sources of energy. Others may espouse a free-market approach,
allowing creative destruction to replace aging technologies and systems with
cleaner, more efficient sources of power.
Shareholder capitalism has
taken its lumps in recent years, no question. And given the complexity of the
issues, it’s unlikely that either the shareholder or stakeholder model of
governance can be analytically proved superior. Yet we see in our work that the
shareholder model, thoughtfully embraced as a collective approach to present
and future value creation, is the best at bridging the broad and varied
interests of shareholders and stakeholders alike.
By
Marc
Goedhart, Tim Koller, and David Wessels
http://www.mckinsey.com/insights/corporate_finance/the_real_business_of_business?cid=other-eml-alt-mip-mck-oth-1503#sthash.8xR0JeZI.dpuf
No comments:
Post a Comment