Prospects for growth: An interview with Robert Solow
The economist who won a Nobel Prize for advancing our understanding of technology looks at the past and future of productivity-led growth.
More
than 50 years have
passed since Robert Solow published the path-breaking model of
economic growth for which he won the Nobel Prize in 1987. This model
proposed that growth occurred not solely from the accumulation of
capital and increase in labor, as previously theorized, but also from
what Solow called “technological progress”—a term now better
known as total-factor-productivity growth, which encompasses advances
in technology as well as in management and organizational techniques.
In the early 1990s, Solow accepted the role of academic adviser to
the then-fledgling McKinsey Global Institute (MGI), which was
proposing to research and explain differences in the productivity of
industries and countries. Economist Martin Neil Baily and McKinsey
Publishing’s Frank Comes recently sat down with Solow to discuss
the implications of those early studies for business and economics,
as well as the prospects for future productivity-led growth.
The Quarterly:
What,
if anything, surprised you about the findings of the early MGI
studies?
Robert
Solow: What
came as something completely new to me was that if you looked at the
same industry across countries, there were almost always dramatic
differences in either labor productivity or total factor
productivity. To my surprise, it turned out that most of the time,
certainly more often than not, the difference in productivity—in
the auto industry or the steel industry or the
residential-construction industry in the US and in countries in
Europe—was not only substantial but couldn’t seriously be
explained by differences in access to technology.
We
also found that the productivity differences could not be traced to
differences in access to investment capital. The French automobile
industry, much to my surprise, turned out to be more capital
intensive than the American automobile industry. So it was not that
either. The MGI studies instead traced these differences in
productivity to organizational differences, to the way tasks were
allocated within a firm or a division—essentially, to failures in
managerial decisions.
I
was, of course, instantly suspicious of this. I figured to myself,
“What do you expect a bunch of management consultants to find but
differences in management capacities? That’s in their genes. That’s
not in my genes.” But MGI made a very convincing case for this. And
I came to believe that it was right.
The
Quarterly:
So
management was the primary factor in productivity differences?
Robert
Solow: Yes,
and there was another surprise, for which there was partly anecdotal,
partly statistical evidence. If you asked why there were differences
that could be erased or diminished by better management, the answer
was that it took the spur of sharp competition to induce managers to
do what they were in principle capable of doing. So the idea that
everybody is everywhere and always maximizing profits turned out to
be not quite right.
MGI
made a very good case that what was lacking in these trailing
industries in other countries—or in the US, in cases where the US
trailed—was enough exposure to competition from whoever in the
world had the best practice. And this, of course, can apply within a
country. We know that in any industry, there is a whole distribution
of productivity levels across firms and even, sometimes, across
establishments within a firm. And much of that must be due to the
absence of any spur to do more.
So
an interesting conclusion to me was that international trade serves a
purpose beyond exploiting comparative advantage. It exposes
high-level managers in various countries to a little fright. And
fright turns out to be an important motivation.
The
Quarterly:
So
competing against the global best-practice leaders is a way to
encourage your own industry to use best practice?
Robert
Solow: Yes,
and it goes beyond that, even. Competing as part of the world economy
is an important way of gaining access to scale. If you’re a Belgian
company or even a French company, it may be that best practice
requires a scale of production larger than the French domestic market
will provide for French producers.
So
it’s important for such companies to have access to the
international market. That was not something I had thought of. And I
don’t think anyone had—at least I had no reason to think, within
economics, that there had been much thought about management
activities as a big difference between best practice and less good
practice. We had always thought, “Well, people seek profits. And if
they seek profits, they’ll have to adopt best practice.” Not so.
The
Quarterly:
Do
you think the lessons from the microsector-level view have changed
the way economists work? Or has this remained outside the economics
profession?
Robert
Solow: I
think it’s been partially absorbed by the economics profession.
There is much more interest in industrial organization, in
competitive advantages and how they work themselves out in
productivity.
The
Quarterly:
Looking
toward the future, are there other issues in economics that MGI’s
sector-level approach might be helpful for?
Robert
Solow: I
would like to see more work on the determinants of productivity and
productivity increases within the service sector. To begin with, I
don’t think we even have a very clear idea about the relative
capital intensity within the service sector or between the service
sector and goods-producing sector.
I
remember I was once writing something in which I was describing the
service sector as being of relatively low capital intensity. And then
I stopped and remembered that the following day I had an appointment
with my dentist and that my dentist’s office was as capital
intensive a 500 square feet as I had ever seen in my life.
So
I think the place where the MGI approach is most needed right now is
in the service sector. There has been service-sector work within MGI,
and outside of it as well, but not as much as is warranted in view of
the 70 percent or more of all employment in advanced economies that’s
in service industries.
The
Quarterly:
Are
there particular places in the service sector where you’d look
first?
Robert
Solow: Well,
that brings me to another MGI result that I found fascinating. At one
point, we were trying to understand the industrial basis, the
sectoral basis, for the acceleration and deceleration of productivity
growth. And one of the things we found was that the two largest
sectoral contributions to the acceleration of productivity growth
when it was accelerating and, presumably, to the deceleration when it
was decelerating came from wholesaling and retailing.1 Both
of them, at the time, were low-productivity sectors and
low-productivity-growth sectors. But they employ so many people that
a slight improvement in the productivity of retailing makes a large
contribution to the increase in national productivity.
There
has been some work on that, but I think the work is needed now more
in personal services. God knows, in healthcare. And education. Or
child care. All sorts of things.
The
Quarterly:
What
do you think about the prospects for future growth?
Robert
Solow: As
an ordinary macroeconomist, I have avoided forecasting as if it were
a foul disease—as indeed it is. It’s very damaging to the
tissues. So I don’t think one can say too much.
But
two things are pretty clear. Everywhere, both in the developed
economies and in the emerging economies, population growth is likely
to be slower, much slower than it has been in the past century. I
don’t know how this is going to go in the very poor parts of the
world, like Africa, but certainly in the emerging economies the
classical demographic transition will take place. And in the
developed economies, population growth is going to slow. So there is
going to be a problem that both of them will face. The motivation for
what we used to call capital widening—simply to provide the
standard capital intensity for an increasing population in areas such
as housing and consumer domestic durables—will be weaker, and that
will certainly slow the total rate of growth.
The
growth of per capita income is a different matter. And there I think
the key issue is economies such as Russia, India, China, Brazil, and
so on. There, industries still have to catch up to the technological
frontier, still have to modernize to achieve the level of
technological advancement that Europe and North America have already
achieved. That catching up, I think, you have to expect to happen. If
it doesn’t happen, that will likely be for political, not economic,
reasons. But leaving aside politics, about which it’s hard to say
anything intelligent, there is still a lot of room for catch-up. And
this needs to be quantitatively analyzed, industry by industry,
because industries catch up, not whole economies.
The
Quarterly:
There
are some very pessimistic folks when it comes to future growth. Bob
Gordon, for example, who thinks that a lot of innovation has run out
of steam. And Larry Summers, whose thoughts about secular stagnation
look at it more from the demand side of the economy. Are you as
pessimistic as they are about the prospects for growth?
Robert
Solow: I’m
not as pessimistic as Bob Gordon about the long-run technological
prospects, because I feel less certain about them than he is. In the
case of Gordon, by the way, I think that to a certain extent he is
concerned not so much with the real-GDP-per-hour-worked side of this
as with how much technology changes our lives. And though we might
conceivably have technological innovations which improve productivity
dramatically, they won’t change life as much as the wheel or, as
Bob Gordon likes to point out, the flush toilet. But I’m not as
pessimistic as Bob Gordon about the future of advanced technology.
I’m just uncertain.
The
secular-stagnation notion is that it may be harder, for the next 50
years, to maintain full utilization of economies than it was in the
last 50 years. One technical way to put it is that the real interest
rate compatible with full utilization might be negative. This is like
Alvin Hansen’s old secular stagnation. In
a way, it rests on running out of profitable investment
opportunities.
Rapid
technological progress, if it entails hardware, is a way of providing
investment opportunities that are profitable. So we have to hope for
that. And as I say, I’m not necessarily pessimistic about that at
all. If slower population growth eliminates some investment
opportunities—those that come from providing a house and a
refrigerator and a washing machine for every family—then if
technological progress slows a little bit, the balance between
diminishing returns and technology could shift a bit in favor of
diminishing returns. The available rates of return on plant and
equipment investment might be a little lower. The motivation to
invest—comparing that with the rate of interest, which can’t fall
below zero—that gap might narrow. And it could get harder to
maintain full employment.
There’s
a good Keynesian answer to this, which involves government
expenditures. But we’re not so great at that and not getting any
better at it either. So I think that there is a case to be made that
it might be harder in the future to generate the investment
spending—the nonincome-induced spending, the autonomous spending,
to use the lingo—that’s needed to maintain full employment and
full utilization.
The
Quarterly:
And
here we are at a time when corporate investment is low.
Robert
Solow: It’s
a little mysterious because corporate profits are very good, and
corporations are sitting on cash. The natural reading of that—but I
don’t know if it’s true—is that they’re worried about their
future profitability, because that’s what would limit their
willingness to invest. Why they are worried about their future
profitability, I don’t know.
The
Quarterly:
What
might be done to accelerate growth? Do you think there are things
that managers could do to spur the US or the global economy?
Robert
Solow: I
take the Milton Friedman point of view here, which is strange for me.
It’s not the business of the individual manager to say, “What
would be good for the health of the economy?” It’s primarily the
business of the individual manager to increase efficiency and
profitability. I think that to the extent top management is paralyzed
by political uncertainty or whatever, that is a kind of funk— a
failure of collective action.
The
Quarterly:
In
the 1980s, you said that we can see IT everywhere but in the
productivity numbers. Do you think that was true then? And if so, did
it remain true?
Robert
Solow: I
think when I made that remark, I was reviewing somebody’s book. It
was true, and now it’s no longer true. You can, in fact, trace the
productivity effects of information technology. In retrospect, and
probably inevitably, there was a lag in learning how to make
effective use of it in manufacturing, in retailing, in wholesaling,
in all sorts of large sectors. But now, I think there’s no doubt
that you can measure big user gains in productivity from the
computer. I don’t think I was wrong when I said that you couldn’t.
I wasn’t predicting the future. I was saying what was true at the
time.
This
interview was conducted by Martin
Neil Baily, who
holds the Bernard L. Schwartz Chair in Economic Policy Development at
the Brookings Institution, and McKinsey Publishing’s Frank
Comes.
No comments:
Post a Comment